• Thanks for stopping by. Logging in to a registered account will remove all generic ads. Please reach out with any questions or concerns.

Canada's Place in the Global Economy

  • Thread starter Thread starter GAP
  • Start date Start date
Status
Not open for further replies.
Yet more dark clouds on the European horizon, according to this article from The New York Times News Service, reproduced under the Fair Dealing provisions (§29) of the Copyright Act from today’s Globe and Mail:

http://www.theglobeandmail.com/report-on-business/economy/britain-grapples-with-debt-of-greek-proportions/article1488285/
Britain grapples with debt of Greek proportions
‘If you really want a fiscal problem, look at the U.K.'

Landon Thomas Jr.

London — The New York Times News Service

Published on Wednesday, Mar. 03, 2010

As Greece's debt troubles batter the euro, Britain has done its utmost to stay above the fray.

Until now, that is. Suddenly, investors are asking if Britain may soon face its own sovereign debt crisis if the government fails to slash its growing budget deficits quickly enough to escape the contagious fears of financial markets.

The pound fell Tuesday to its lowest level against the dollar in nearly 10 months. The yield on 10-year government bonds, known as gilts, slid as investors fretted that Parliament would be too fragmented after a crucial election in May to whip Britain's messy finances back into shape.

The slide in the pound followed a sharper decline Monday after polls released over the weekend indicated that the opposition Conservatives had lost their clear lead in the election race.

Without a strong political majority to tackle Britain's lumbering fiscal problems, investors could start to make it greatly more expensive for the government to raise funds, setting the stage for a potential double-dip recession, if not worse.

“If you really want a fiscal problem, look at the U.K.,” said Mark Schofield, a fixed-income strategist at Citigroup. “In Europe, the average deficit is about 6 per cent of GDP and in the U.K. it's 12 per cent. It is only just beginning.”

Since the Labour government's intense fiscal intervention in 2008 and 2009, yields on British government debt have soared to among the highest in Europe. And on a broader scale, which includes the borrowing of households and companies, the overall level of debt in Britain is the second-largest in the world, after Japan's, at 380 per cent of the country's gross domestic product, according to a recent report by the consulting company McKinsey.

In recent weeks, the focus has been on debt scofflaws in Europe like Greece, Portugal and Spain, countries where borrowing costs have shot up in line with their growing deficits as investors demanded higher rates to compensate them for the added risk of lending the governments money.

But the recent plunge in the value of the pound below $1.50 and the gradual move upward of Britain's benchmark 10-year borrowing rate on gilts to above 4 per cent suggest that investors are now getting ready to reassess the country's fiscal condition.

Britain is not in the 16-nation euro zone and, unlike Greece and other struggling countries that use the currency, it retains control over its monetary policy. As a result, it has benefited so far from a huge bond-buying program undertaken by the Bank of England  - proportionally, the largest in the world - that has kept mortgage rates and gilt yields at unusually low levels. That means the government and its citizens have been able to continue to borrow at interest rates that do not reflect their true financial situation.
Indeed, the increase in private and government debt here contrasts sharply with the deleveraging that has been going on in the United States.

British household debt is now 170 per cent of overall annual income, compared with 130 per cent in the United States. In an echo of America's rush into subprime mortgages with low teaser rates, millions of homeowners in Britain have piled into variable-rate mortgages that are linked to the rock-bottom base rate.

As for the British government, it has been able to finance a budget deficit of 12.5 per cent of GDP - equal to Greece's - at an interest rate more than two full percentage points lower only because the Bank of England bought the majority of the bonds it issued last year.

“It's not just ‘basket cases' like Greece that can be considered candidates for sovereign crises,” said Simon White of Variant Perception, a research house in London that caters to hedge funds and wealthy individuals. “Gilts and sterling will continue to come under pressure as scrutiny of the U.K. fiscal situation intensifies.”

Adding to this concern is the precarious condition of the British consumer. As interest rates  have hit new lows, the popularity of variable-rate loans has grown. At the end of December, 40 per cent of new mortgages were tracking the government's base rate.
Despite comments from Mervyn King, the governor of the Bank of England, that he might restart his quantitative easing program in light of current economic weakness, the view among investors is growing that interest rates here will rise further, along with higher inflation and Britain's increased risk profile.

In a speech this year, Andrew Haldane, the executive director of financial stability at the Bank of England, warned about how vulnerable Britain was to a rate increase, pointing out that an increase of one percentage point would cause debt service costs relative to income to double, to 13 per cent.

“This is a ticking time bomb,” said Nick Hopkinson of Property Portfolio Rescue, a company that assists overleveraged homeowners. “There are over 400,000 people who are in arrears with their mortgage rates the cheapest they have ever been. When rates increase, a lot of people will be tipped over the edge.”

As a result, those counting on the British consumer to take up the slack from any scaling back of government borrowing could be in for a shock.

Consider Sheridan King, a sales manager who is struggling to pay off his £32,000 in nonmortgage debt. Far from thinking about going shopping, his first priority is keeping clear of his creditors. And even though his variable mortgage of about £100,000 carries a very low rate, interest costs are already chewing up a substantial portion of his pay, and he is deeply worried about the future. “If rates go up, it will be a very dangerous situation for me,” Mr. King said. “It might lead me to consider bankruptcy.”

For the time being, at least, the British government faces no such threat.

Despite its borrowing and spending excesses, Britain still maintains a triple-A credit rating and much of its debt is long term. But with 29 per cent of British bonds held by foreigners, Britain, like Greece, remains highly vulnerable to the vicissitudes of outside investors.

Since early this year, foreign holdings of British bonds have fallen from 35 per cent, a trend that has tracked the pound's decline and contributed to the increase in the yield on its 10-year gilts.

As to which political party he thinks is best placed to handle these challenges, Mr. King takes a skeptical view.

“We are just struggling to get by with all this debt,” he said. “It's time the government got its house in order.”

I agree with Mark Schofield, a fixed-income strategist at Citigroup, that Britain has a serious fiscal problem; crisis is not too strong a word, just like the PIIGS (Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece and Spain) and just like France and several other European countries …

.
.
.
.
.

... and just like America, too.

Canada is not immune to all this: these nations with fiscal crises are our major markets and trading partners; they buy our resources and products and invest in our economy. About the best we can do is to defend ourselves by containing (or restraining) some necessary spending, like defence spending and transfers to provinces for healthcare, and by cutting most spending, including that which is very popular amongst many, many Canadians.
 
A look at how Canada stacks up against other nations in terms of debt:
 
So what happens when everyone starts to default on their obligations?

http://www.nytimes.com/2010/03/06/world/europe/06iceland.html?partner=rss&emc=rss&pagewanted=print

Iceland Voters Set to Reject Debt Deal
By SARAH LYALL

REYKJAVIK, Iceland — After the dust began to settle last year — after the banks failed, the currency collapsed, the stock market crashed and the government fell — the dazed inhabitants of Iceland woke up to another unpleasant problem: They owed, it seemed, some $5.3 billion to more than 300,000 angry people in the Netherlands and Britain.

These were the customers of Icesave, a now notorious online retail branch of the Icelandic bank Landsbanki, which went bankrupt in October 2008 along with 85 percent of Iceland’s banking system. The British and Dutch governments reimbursed their citizens, but then demanded that Iceland repay the money, the equivalent of $65,000 per household here, plus interest.

To put it in perspective, it is as if American taxpayers were being forced to pay $5 trillion (plus interest) to reimburse customers of the Japanese branch of a failed private American bank, said Magnus Arni Skulason, the head of InDefence, a group agitating for a better deal.

The question of how to pay has convulsed this tiny country of about 319,000 people, severely damaging its international reputation and paralyzing its economic recovery. It has so incensed its residents that on Saturday they are expected to reject overwhelmingly the latest Icesave repayment plan, in the first national referendum ever held here on any subject.

The vote raises larger questions about Iceland’s place in the world, said Silja B. Omarsdottir, a political scientist at the University of Iceland. “Are we going to be a country that takes our obligations seriously? Or are we going to say, ‘No, we’re going to do things our way’ and be an international pariah?”

In the scheme of world debt, $5.3 billion is small potatoes. But it represents more than 40 percent of Iceland’s gross domestic product. The interest alone would eat up one-fourth of the country’s revenues, said Prime Minister Johanna Sigurdardottir, who called finding a resolution to the Icesave dispute “a matter of life and death for the Icelandic economy.”

The referendum was prompted on Jan. 5 by the refusal of Iceland’s president, Olafur Ragnar Grimsson, to sign into law the latest Icesave agreement, arrived at after months of bad-tempered negotiations with Britain and the Netherlands and narrowly passed by a divided and fractious Icelandic Parliament.

Mr. Grimsson’s move was unexpected but widely popular in a place that feels bullied and ill treated.

The crisis spurred a series of demonstrations from usually phlegmatic Icelanders, who recited poetry and tossed yogurt pots and rocks at government buildings to protest what they deemed the greed, ineptitude and spinelessness of the governing elite. Nearly a quarter of the electorate signed an Internet petition against the Icesave deal.

The referendum is being closely watched abroad, where the worry is that people in other financially flailing countries might be emboldened to rise up and refuse to honor financial obligations stemming from the failures of their banks.

But absurdities abound. For one thing, Icesave negotiations have moved on since January, so the deal being voted on — which would give Iceland 15 years to repay the money, at 5.5 percent interest — is not the deal currently on the table. For another thing, many Icelanders appear to believe that they are voting not on the terms of the plan, but on whether to pay at all.

Not only that, Ms. Sigurdardottir said, further delays are likely to eat up any savings that might come if all the parties finally agree to a better deal. Iceland has promised to pay up to 20,887 euros per customer (more than $28,000 each), in accordance with European deposit-guarantee regulations, but negotiations are now stalled by arguments over interest rates.

Birgitta Jonsdottir, a member of Parliament from the fledgling people-power Civic Movement Party, said that a “no” vote would send a strong message to the world.

First, she said, “We don’t believe in the socialization of private debt.” Second: “It is time for Britain to treat us like a sovereign nation and not a colony.” And third: “They can’t use the I.M.F. to blackmail us into doing what they want on Icesave.”

But it seems they can.

The I.M.F. and a coalition of Nordic countries have delayed the second installment of a $4.85 billion bailout package for Iceland pending the outcome of the Icesave dispute. The rating agency Fitch recently downgraded Iceland’s credit rating to below investment grade, and Moody’s and Standard & Poor’s both warned that the political and financial turmoil expected to follow if the deal was rejected might make them follow suit.

Britain is also threatening to hold up Iceland’s entry to the European Union.

A “no” vote “would effectively be saying that Iceland doesn’t want to be part of the international financial system,” Lord Myners, financial services secretary to Britain’s treasury, warned in January.

That some Icelanders seem willing to take the consequences — to risk becoming “the Cuba of the north,” in the words of Mr. Skulason — speaks to an element embedded deep in the national character. The symbol of this is Bjartur, the protagonist of Iceland’s most celebrated work of fiction, “Independent People,” by Halldor Laxness (who is also the only person here to have won a Nobel Prize).

Bjartur, a sheep farmer, struggles through one disaster after another to survive in the punishing Icelandic countryside and pay off his mortgage.

“He represents the Icelandic soul,” said Ms. Omarsdottir, the political scientist. “He’d rather have his kids starve, his wife die — his two wives die — and his cow die, and lose almost all of his sheep, than be beholden to anyone.”

Iceland’s economy is all but stalled as everyone waits for a resolution. Businesses cannot get loans. Foreign currency movement is severely restricted. Unemployment has increased to about 8 percent from less than 1 percent. The economy contracted by 7 percent last year.

Iceland’s three McDonald’s outlets closed in October, saying that they were losing money because of the collapse of Iceland’s currency, the krona, and that to make a profit, they would have had to charge $6.36 for a Big Mac.

Many Icelanders see Saturday’s vote as an expression of outrage not just against foreign interference but also against Icelandic bankers. These were the so-called Vikings who at the height of the boom ran wild around the world making complicated, house-of-cards deals and encouraging a once prudent population to buy bigger houses and fancy cars in foreign currency.

Iceland has foreign debts of $1.36 billion that mature at the end of 2011. No one is predicting, yet, that it could default on those loans, but delays in Icesave will not help matters.

“In the worst case, in 20 years we will be like Cuba, with lots of old cars,” Elisabet Run Sigurdardottir, 22, a student, said in a downtown coffee shop the other day.

She was joking, mostly. “Only our old cars will be Range Rovers.”
 
I know that almost no one, except me, cares about all this, but we all should because guys like Olivier Blanchard want to debase our currencies and impoverish us and our children and grandchildren so that a few bureaucrats can manage the global economy:

http://network.nationalpost.com/NP/blogs/fullcomment/archive/2010/03/08/terence-corcoran-macroimprudential-monetary-policy.aspx
Macroimprudential monetary policy

March 08, 2010

Should inflation be deliberately pushed up to 4%? This destructive idea is sweeping financial markets. Canada beware. 

By Terence Corcoran

For some time now global economic theory has been more or less settled on the idea that the best inflation rate is low inflation, at least 2% or possibly even zero. But now, suddenly, the financial world is bristling with the idea that in these troubled times the world economy needs a fresh approach to inflation, even a new target range of, say, 4%.


The source of this proposal is the International Monetary Fund, home of the world’s greatest noodlers on how to impose a sweeping new era of global macroprudential economic regulation aimed at avoiding future economic crises. Few people thought that what the world needed to create economic stability was a steady stream of destabilizing inflation, but now that the IMF has unleashed the idea it has been slowly traveling through the lower reaches of the economic theocracies and is now making its way into the capital markets as a serious policy alternative.


This impausible debate hasn’t yet reached Canada yet, where the Bank of Canada is formally committed to 2% inflation. But if the idea that higher inflation is good policy should gain traction elsewhere in this crazy new Keynesian world, Canadian monetary policy—not to mention the Canadian dollar, fiscal policies and investment strategies—would be thrown for a loop, which is economic jargon for shock and chaos. Do you like your Canadian dollar at US$1.15 or US$1.25?


It all began a month ago when Olivier Blanchard, chief economist of at the IMF, co-authored a paper, Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy, in which he and two colleagues mused about the possible benefits of a deliberately high-inflation policy. The paper mentioned 4% as a specific target, a shocking number in itself. Two European bankers, Alex Weber and Philipp Hildebrand, tackled the Blanchard proposal in a recent Wall Street Journal commentary. As they put it, the IMF’s chief economist is promoting a monetary illusion.


The destructive potential and risks associated with a deliberate unleashing of 4% inflation are alarming enough—money loses half its value every 10 years, robbing citizens and distorting economic calculation. High inflation also threatens currency and price shocks across the global economy. These are grounds enough for rejecting the idea. But there are other equally powerful arguments against the Blanchard inflation regime, arguments embedded in the IMF paper.


A core rationale in the paper is that a high inflation regime opens the door to a new regulatory regime, one that involves a major expansion of government control over a wide range of economic activities.

The paper begins with the obvious statement that there are limits to fiscal policy and the use of government spending to stimulate economic activity in times of crisis. At low inflation rates, there also appear to be limits to monetary policy. Once interest rates have been set close to zero, as they are today in many countries, the impact of monetary policy is also limited. If the inflation target were 4%, then nominal interest rates would today be higher, and that would make it possible for the world’s central banks to cut interest rates in times of crisis. “As a matter of logic,” said Mr. Blanchard, “higher average inflation and thus higher average nominal interest rates before the crisis would have given more room for monetary policy to be eased during the crisis and would have resulted in less deterioration in fiscal positions. “


What we need to think about now, said Mr. Blanchard, is whether this could justify setting a higher inflation target in the future. If nominal  interest rates were at 6% and inflation at 4% then the economy could be stimulated with central banks pushing rates.


But what Mr. Blanchard really wants is an ongoing excuse to expand the role of government. If the inflation he proposes distorts markets, then it is the role of government to intervent to manipulate the markets to avoid and neutralize those distortions. The list of regulatory interventions needed to offset inflation soon becomes vast under Mr. Blanchard’s proposals.


New regulation and “instruments” would have to be brought in to manage bubbles and asset surges, recalibrate systemic risks, and fine-tune economic activity through any number of shocks.


He calls them “cyclical regulatory tools.” For example, if leverage appears excessive in the markets, regulatory capital ratios can be increased. If liquidity appears to low, regulatory liquidity ratios can be introduced.  If house prices rise, loan-to-capial ratios can be decreased. To limit stock price increases, margin requirements can be increases. The tax system would also have to be rejigged to take account of inflation in capital gains and bracket creep. What about wage indexation and its ability to send inflation soaring? Mr. Blanchard stopped short of price controls, although it is hard to know why they were left out of his calculus.


The questions in Mr. Blanchard’s paper seem familiar. “Should policy makers therefor aim for a higher target inflation rate in normal times, in order to increase the room for monetary policy to reach to such shocks? To be concrete, are the net costs of inflation much higher at, say, 4% than at 2%, the current target range? Is it more difficult to anchor expectations at 4% than at 2%?”


These are questions long thought to have been answered. But in the new world of macroprudential regulation, they apparently must now all be answered anew.


Blanchard is proposing macroeconomic rubbish but Europe (France, in particular) has long been the source of a huge, pent up desire to disable the free market and impose state controls on everyone and everything.
 
Cripes, this is scary stuff. High (or moderate) inflation has a certain allure for the big government types. It reduces annual deficits in real terms as time goes on, as the annual repayments are effectively reduced year over year. This was the kind of loopy thinking that drove Canadian officialdom in the late seventies and early eighties, and nearly reduced us to third world status.

It is nothing but a massive ponzi scheme.
 
Some others do care about this stuff.

I think that its kind of late to be worrying about inflationary targets.  IMHO inflation has been an implicit goal of the IMF at least since the seventies.  They may have turned the heat down a little in the 80s and 90s to a 2-3% level after discovering that the markets, and politics, couldn't cope with 10-20% levels, but ultimately the intent is to redistribute the wealth. 

Print more dollars, euros, carbon credits ..... whatever, and thus debase the holdings of the "rich" while concurrently putting scrip in the hands of those that didn't have it before and making them forever grateful to Government and the State for putting shoes on their feet and making the trains run on time.

Real value is still reckoned in Gold Sovereigns and Silver Dollars per Barrel of Oil.
 
Impoverishing the poor is the end result of inflation, so this creates an underclass that is susceptible to demagogues and political manipulation.

Sadly the only real way to end inflation may be to go back to the system of "free banking" (where individual banks  have the power to create or deflate the money supply based on their holdings of real wealth and financial assets) rather than allow governments to create money through the central bank. This will probably not happen in an orderly fashion but only as a result of an inflationary or hyper-inflationary collapse.
 
Looking at this mountain of debt, default is starting to look like the only rational option after all:

http://www.sortofpolitical.com/2010/03/nothing-like-little-bit-of-perspective.html

Nothing like a little bit of perspective...

CNBC has a list up that definitely puts Canada's federal deficit and debt into perspective: The World's Biggest Debtor Nations

To be clear, I'm no advocate of deficit spending or debt financing by governments. However, some times it's unavoidable.

That said, Canada's external debt as a percentage of GDP, roughly 60% , isn't even anywhere near being in the same league as the following! Not even remotely close! And correct me if I'm wrong, but I think it's worth noting that most of this list is made up of left leaning quasi-socialist states.

External debt as a percentage of GDP...

20. United States
External debt (as % of GDP): 95.9%
Gross external debt: $13.67 trillion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $14.25 trillion

19. Australia
External debt (as % of GDP): 108.8%
Gross external debt: $891.26 billion (2009 Q2)
2009 GDP (est): $819 billion

18. Hungary
External debt (as % of GDP): 124.2%
Gross external debt: $231.33 billion (2009 Q2)
2009 GDP (est): $186.3 billion

17. Italy
External debt (as % of GDP): 154.6%
Gross external debt: $2.71 trillion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $1.76 trillion

16. Greece
External debt (as % of GDP): 175.3%
Gross external debt: $594.60 billion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $339.2 billion

15. Spain
External debt (as % of GDP): 184.7%
Gross external debt: $2.53 trillion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $1.37 trillion

14. Germany
External debt (as % of GDP): 189.4%
Gross external debt: $5.33 trillion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $2.81 trillion

13. Finland
External debt (as % of GDP): 205.7%
Gross external debt: $376.8 billion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $183.1 billion

12. Norway
External debt (as % of GDP): 208.9%
Gross external debt: $577.80 billion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $276.5 billion

11. Hong Kong
External debt (as % of GDP): 218.8%
Gross external debt: $659.27 billion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $301.3 billion

10. Portugal
External debt (as % of GDP): 231.5%
Gross external debt: $538.1 billion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $232.4 billion

9. France
External debt (as % of GDP): 247.2%
Gross external debt: $5.22 trillion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $2.11 trillion

8. Austria
External debt (as % of GDP): 268.9%
Gross external debt: $869.13 billion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $323.2 billion

7. Sweden
External debt (as % of GDP): 275%
Gross external debt: $916.42 billion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $333.2 billion

6. Denmark
External debt (as % of GDP): 315.2%
Gross external debt: $627.6 billion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $199.1 billion

5. Belgium
External debt (as % of GDP): 345.6%
Gross external debt: $1.32 trillion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $381.4 billion

4. Switzerland
External debt (as % of GDP): 390%
Gross external debt: $1.23 trillion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $316.1 billion

3. Netherlands
External debt (as % of GDP): 395.6%
Gross external debt: $2.58 trillion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $652 billion

2. United Kingdom
External debt (as % of GDP): 427.6%
Gross external debt: $9.26 trillion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $2.17 trillion

1. Ireland
External debt (as % of GDP): 1,352%
Gross external debt: $2.39 trillion (2009 Q3)
2009 GDP (est): $177.3 billion

Can we say, "YIKES!!!"???
 
More on popping bubbles:

http://baselinescenario.com/2010/03/11/the-coming-greek-debt-bubble/

The Coming Greek Debt Bubble

By Peter Boone and Simon Johnson

Bubbles are back as a topic of serious discussion, as they were before the financial crisis.  The questions are: (1) can you spot bubbles, (2) can policymakers do anything to deflate them gently, and (3) can anyone make money when bubbles get out of control?

Our answers are: Spotting pure equity bubbles may sometimes be hard, but we can always see unsustainable finances supported by cheap credit.  But policymakers will not act because all great (and dangerous) bubbles build their own political support; bubbles are invincible, until they collapse.  A few investors can do well by betting against such bubbles, but it’s harder than you might think because you have to get the timing right – and that’s much more about luck than skill.

Bubbles are usually associated with runaway real estate prices (think Japan in the 1980s and the US more recently) or emerging market booms (parts of Asia in the 1990s and, some begin to argue, China today) or just the stock market gone mad (remember pets.com?)  But they are a much more general phenomenon – any time the actual market value for any asset diverges from a reasonable estimate of its “fundamental” value.

To think about this more specifically, consider the case of Greece today.  It might seem odd to suggest there is a bubble in a country so evidently under financial pressure – and working hard to stave off collapse with the help of its neighbors – but the important thing about bubbles is: Don’t listen to the “market color” (otherwise known as ex post rationalization), just look at the numbers.

By the end of 2011 Greece’s debt will around 150% of GDP (the numbers here are based on the 2009 IMF Article IV assessment; we make some adjustments for the worsening economy and the restating of numbers since that time – for example, the fiscal deficit in 2009 will likely turn out to be about 8 percent, which is double what the IMF expected until recently).  About 80 percent of this debt is foreign owned, and a large part of this is thought held by residents of France and Germany.  Every 1 percentage point rise in interest rates means Greece needs to send an additional 1.2 percent of GDP abroad to those bondholders.

What if Greek interest rates rise to, say, 10% – a modest premium for a country which has the highest external public debt/GDP ratio in the world, which continues (under the so-called “austerity” program) to refinance even the interest on that debt without actually paying a centime out of its own pocket, and which is struggling to establish any sustained backing from the rest of Europe?  Greece would need to send at total of 12% of GDP abroad per year, once they rollover the existing stock of debt to these new rates (nearly half of Greek debt will roll over within 3 years).

This is simply impossible and unheard of for any long period of history.  German reparation payments were 2.4 percent of GNP during 1925-32, and in the years immediately after 1982, the net transfer of resources from Latin America was 3.5 percent of GDP (a fifth of its export earnings).  Neither of these were good experiences.

On top of all this Greece’s debt, even under the IMF’s mild assumptions, is on a non-convergent path even with the perceived “austerity” measures.  Bubble math is easy.  Hide all the names and just look at the numbers.  If debt looks like it will explode as a percent of GDP, then a spectacular collapse is in the cards.

Seen in this comparative perspective, Greece is bankrupt today without a great deal more European assistance or without a much more drastic austerity program. Probably they need both.

Given there’s a definite bubble in Greek debt, should we expect European politicians to help deflate this gradually?  Definitely not – in fact, it is their misleading statements, supported in recent days (astonishingly) by the head of the International Monetary Fund, that keep the debt bubble going and set us all up for a greater crash later.

The French and Germans are apparently actually encouraging banks, pension funds, and individuals to buy these bonds – despite the fact senior politicians must surely know this is a Ponzi scheme, i.e., people can get out of Greek bonds only to the extent that new investors come in.  At best, this does nothing more than postpone the crisis – in the business, it is known as “kicking the can down the road.”  At worst, it encourages less informed people (including perhaps pension funds) to buy bonds as smarter people (and big banks, surely) take the opportunity to exit.

While the French and German leadership makes a great spectacle of wanting to end speculation, in fact they are instead encouraging it.  The hypocrisy is horrifying – Mr. Sarkozy and Ms. Merkel are helping realistic speculators make money on the backs of those who take seriously misleading statements by European politicians.  This is irresponsible.

What should be done?

1.  The Greeks and the Europeans must decide:  do they want to keep the euro, or not.

2.  If they want to keep the euro in Greece, the Greeks need to come up with realistic plan to start paying back debt soon.  Any Greek plan will not be credible for the first few years, so the Europeans must finance the Greeks fully. This does not mean 20bn euros, it means making available around 180bn euros – i.e., the full amount of refinancing that Greece needs during this period.

3.  If they don’t want to keep the euro then they should start working now on a plan for Greece’s withdrawal.  The northern Europeans will need to bail out their own banks, because Greek debt must fall substantially in value – euro denominated debt will need to be written down substantially or converted to drachmas so it will be partially inflated away.  The Greeks can convert local contracts, and deposits at banks, into drachma.  It will be a very messy, difficult transition, but the more the debt bubble persists, the more attractive this becomes as a “least awful” solution.

Regardless of the decision on whether Greece will keep the drachma or give it up , the IMF should be brought in to conduct the monitoring and burden share.  The Europeans flagrant deception which we now observe – claiming the Greeks have made a big step and encouraging people to buy Greek bonds – proves they do not have the political capacity to be realistic about this situation.  Who can now be believed on needs for Greek financial reform and what is truly a credible response?  The only credible voice left with the capacity to act is the IMF – and even the Fund risks being compromised by the indiscreet statements of its top leadership as the bubble continues.

If such measures are not taken, we are clearly heading for a train wreck.  The European politicians have been tested, and now we know the results:  They are not careful, they are reckless.

My big question is how would anyone not named George Soros make any money off this? (Imagine an Army.ca pool investing in means of cashing in on the deflating bubbles of Greek, PIIGS, Japanese or other heavily indebted nations debt obligations...)
 
And more on foreign debt holdings:

http://corner.nationalreview.com/post/?q=ODMyM2YzYjk1YzI4ZGNkNjYxNDQyMTk2ZmEyNmM4Zjg=

Is Foreign Ownership of Our Debt a Threat to the U.S.? 
[Veronique de Rugy]

This is the question that economist Bruce Bartlett asks this morning over at Forbes. As with all his articles, Bartlett tackles an interesting issue. It's one where people have many preconceptions that are incorrect. As always, he does a terrific job at explaining the problem and its implications (especially since this time he refrains for saying that the only solution to our fiscal troubles is the implementation of a VAT without even reforming entitlement spending.)

First, let me say that foreigners own much less of our debt than you may think. I made this chart to show how much our debt "held by the public" is held by foreigners versus domestic investors.

Until the 1970s, Bartlett explains, foreigners owned less than 5 percent of our debt. Today, they own roughly 50 percent. That share is increasing as we can see in this chart.

Second, the Chinese own less of our debt than you may think. According to the Treasury Department, they own $894 billion out of the $3.6 trillion owned by foreigners. Bartlett argues that Chinese ownership is likely understated and is probably over $1 trillion.

But should we care that the Chinese or others own so much of our debt? Not really, Bartlett explains:

"The Chinese dilemma reminds me of a quip once made by economist John Maynard Keynes: "Owe your banker £1,000 and you are at his mercy; owe him £1 million and the position is reversed." (The quote can be found in his collected writings, vol. 24, p. 258.)"

It doesn't mean that we should be complacent about this increased foreign ownership of our debt. But, as long as the national debt is denominated in dollars, we are okay. To the extent that there is a risk it is the following: if foreign investors fear that the dollar will drop against their currency they could demand a higher interest rates as compensation, or they could  insist that the Treasury issue bonds denominated in foreign currencies. This would be bad because it would shift all the foreign exchange risk to the taxpayer.

As Bartlett notes:

"While the U.S. Treasury has never issued bonds denominated in foreign currencies, it is conceivable that it could be forced to do so if the dollar falls sharply and foreign demand for U.S. bonds wanes. That will be the point at which our debt problem becomes more than theoretical and we are really on the road to national bankruptcy."
 
When does your "debt" become my "investment"?

If I encourage the bank to invest in me doesn't that mean that I incur a debt to the bank?

This article makes the point that that balance of investment has been skewed by the value of non-US holdings decreasing faster than the value of US holdings while concurrently foreigners have been fleeing insecure markets for the relative security of the US market.

Similarly in Canada.  Our nationalists demand freedom of action by also demanding that Canada free itself from foreign investments.

And yet it was foreign investment in the Beaver business (100 Companions, HBC and Northwest Company), the canals and railways, the lumber mills, the mines and the auto and aviation industries that created the wealthy country Canada has become - the country that can support the greedy population of a large metropolitan area in China, or a single state in the US, while laying claim to resources of land, minerals and water greater than all other Nation-States save one.

Foreign debt isn't necessarily bad.  Just like my mortgage isn't necessarily bad.  Just so long as I can service the carrying charges.
 
Kirkhill said:
Foreign debt isn't necessarily bad.  Just like my mortgage isn't necessarily bad.  Just so long as I can service the carrying charges.

Of course the question on everyone's mind is if these carrying charges can be sustained (to give you an ides of the scale and scope, Canada spends @ $30 billion/year in our debt carrying charges). Here is the other half of the equation; what if no one is available to make new loans anymore?

http://money.ca.msn.com/investing/jim-jubak/article.aspx?cp-documentid=23629700

Is China actually bankrupt?

The nation has erected a complex system for magically making its debts disappear, but a look up China's sleeve shows that its IOUs may equal its GDP.

Jim Jubak

Is China broke?

It seems like a silly question, right? China's foreign-exchange reserves stood at $2.4 trillion at the end of 2009. Yes, China announced that its proposed annual budget for 2010 would produce a record deficit, but the deficit is just $154 billion, or 2.8% of China's gross domestic product. In contrast, the Congressional Budget Office projects the U.S. budget deficit for fiscal 2010 at $1.3 trillion. That's equal to 9.2% of GDP.

But remember the theme of my column earlier this week: All governments lie about their finances. At worst, as in Greece and the United States, the lies are bold and transparent. Everybody knows the emperor has no clothes, but no one want to say so. At best, as in Canada and China, the lies are more subtle -- more like a magician's misdirection than a viking raider's axe. Look at these great numbers, the lie goes, but don't look at those up my sleeve.

There's a good argument to be made that if you look at all the numbers, instead of just the ones the budget magicians want you to see, China is indeed broke.

More debt than meets the eye
Want to see how that could be?

If you look only at the current position of China's national government, the country is in great shape. Not only is the current budget deficit at that tiny 2.8% of GDP, but the International Monetary Fund projects the country's accumulated gross debt at just 22% of 2010 GDP. U.S gross debt, by comparison, is projected at 94% of GDP in 2010. The lowest gross-debt-to-GDP figure for any of the Group of Seven developed economies is Canada's 79%.

But China has a history of taking debt off its books and burying it, which should prompt us to poke and prod its numbers. If we go back to the last time China cooked the national books big time, during the Asian currency crisis of 1997, we can get an idea of where its debt might be hidden now.

The currency crisis started in 1997 with the collapse of the Thai baht -- and then, like dominoes, the currencies of Indonesia, South Korea, Malaysia and the Philippines collapsed.

In each case, the country had built up an export-led economy financed by foreign debt. When the hot money that had been flowing in instead flowed out, that sent currencies, stock markets and economies into a nose dive.

China escaped the first stage of the crisis because the country's tightly controlled currency and stock markets, and its economy, had kept out hot money from overseas. China had built its export-led economy on domestic bank loans instead. The majority of bank loans, then as now, went to state-owned companies -- about 70% of the total, the Congressional Research Service estimated in a 1999 examination of the period.

Those loans were all that kept the doors open at many of China's biggest state-owned companies. In its review, the Congressional Research Service estimated that about 75% of China's 100,000 largest state-owned companies lost money and needed bank loans to continue operating.

That became a problem when, in the aftermath of the currency crisis, China's exports fell. That sent revenue plunging at state-owned companies that were already losing money. Suddenly, China's banks were sitting on billions and billions of debts that anybody who'd taken Bookkeeping 1 in high school could tell were never going to be paid. This was especially a problem for China's biggest banks, all of which had ambitions to raise more capital -- and their international profile -- by going public in Hong Kong and New York. But no bank could go public with this much bad debt on its books.

What to do? Why not bury the bad debt?

The Beijing government created special-purpose asset management companies for the four largest state-owned banks, the Industrial and Commercial Bank of China (IDCBY.N), the Agricultural Bank of China, the Bank of China (BACHY.N) and China Construction Bank (CICHY.N). These asset management companies -- China Cinda, China Huarong, China Orient and China Great Wall -- would ultimately wind up buying $287 billion in bad loans from state-owned banks. The majority of those purchases were at book value.

So how did the asset management companies pay for the purchase of that $287 billion in bad loans? They certainly didn't pay cash. Instead, they issued bonds to the banks in exchange for the bad loans. The bonds, of course, were backed by the promise that the asset management companies would gradually sell off or collect on the bad loans in time to redeem the bonds. And in the meantime, they'd pay the banks interest on those bonds.

Neat, huh? In one swell foop, the state-owned banks got $287 billion in bad loans off their books and turned deadbeat loans that would never pay off into streams of income from these bonds. To read more on this neat bit of financial engineering, check out this research paper (.pdf file).

Of course, that still left the little issue of where the asset management companies were going to get the approximately $30 billion in annual interest they had promised to pay the state-owned banks. There was also the small matter of how they were going to pay off these bonds when they came due in 10 years, especially since the cash recovery rate on these bad loans would run at just 20.3% in the first five years.

Fast-forward financing

But who really cared? The Beijing government and the state-owned banks had kicked the problem 10 years down the road. (A favourite tactic of politicians, Republicans, Democrats and Communists alike, is to punt, so that today's problem becomes somebody else's problem in the future.) The bonds issued by the asset management companies didn't have an explicit government guarantee, but everybody assumed that at some future date the government would either pay up or punt again.

The 10-year punt of 1999 came to earth in 2009, and, lo and behold, there was more magic.

In some cases -- China Huarong, for example -- the asset management companies simply declared that they'd done disposing of bad debts, that profits were soaring and that they were seeking strategic partners in preparation for a public offering.

In others cases, the magic was more complex. In October 2009, for example, China Cinda said it had secured government approval for a restructuring plan that would create a company to dispose of the $30 billion in bad loans still on Cinda's books. The company said it would then look for strategic partners in preparation for a public offering.

Who in their right minds would be a strategic partner and investor in one of these asset management companies? Well, how about one of the original state-owned banks, China Construction Bank, that Cinda had bought the bad loans from in the first place. "The hardest thing," China Construction Bank Chairman Guo Shuqing said in an Oct. 17, 2009, interview, "is evaluation."

Really? When the government runs the books, does all the accounting and decides what assets to send where, I think evaluation would be very easy. Any wonder, then, that today's huge run-up in loans -- and bad loans -- by China's banks is making some critics nervous?

The bigger problem, though, isn't so much China's big banks but the country's local governments.

Thinking globally, hiding (debt) locally

By now, everyone who has a nickel in China, or a dime itching to get into China, knows that the country's banks went on a lending spree in 2009. On top of official government stimulus spending of $585 billion, banks, encouraged by the government, doubled their lending in 2009 to $1.4 trillion from the previous year.

(Please remember when judging these figures that China's economy was an estimated $4.8 trillion in GDP in 2009, according to the CIA World Factbook. Estimated U.S. GDP was about three times larger, at $14.3 trillion. So China's 2009 bank lending of $1.4 trillion would be equal to lending of $4.2 trillion in the United States, and China's $585 billion government stimulus package would equal a $1.7 trillion U.S. package, more than twice the $787 billion size of the U.S. stimulus package of February 2009.)

China's banks hit the ground running even harder in 2010, lending out an additional $309 billion in January and February. If the banks had continued at that rate, they would have passed the official lending ceiling of $1.1 trillion by August. (See my Jan. 14 column for more on the lending boom and its results.)

So China's banking regulators, spooked by the increase in bank lending, tightened the reins. For 2010, they set a lending target 20% lower than 2009 lending levels. They raised reserve requirements so banks would have less capital to lend. And they told banks to hit the capital markets to raise an estimated $90 billion through 2011. (See this blog post for more.)

It's not clear that those steps will be enough to balance the huge number of bad loans that China's banks made during the lending boom. But China's regulators have clearly learned a lot about how to address a bad loan problem in the banking system since the 1997 currency crisis.

But as the U.S. Federal Reserve has so amply demonstrated over the past decade, regulators tend to gear up to fight the last war. That leaves them vulnerable to the next crisis precisely to the degree by which it differs from the last one.

China's new debt problem is the thousands of investment companies set up by local governments to borrow money from banks and then lend it to local companies.

By law, China's local governments can't borrow directly. But the incentives for local governments to set up investment companies were huge.

By making loans to local companies, local governments could produce thousands of jobs and drive up the value of local enterprises. And by funding commercial and residential construction, they could drive up the price of land. Those results were important to local officials who often profited personally, but they were also essential to the survival of local governments. By law, those units also aren't allowed to raise their own taxes for local expenditures. To meet local demands -- and to fulfill the directives issued by Beijing -- local governments are dependent on frequently inadequate revenue transfers from Beijing and what they can collect from such transactions as local real-estate sales.

So how much did these investment companies borrow and then lend?

Local-government investment companies had a total of $1.7 trillion in outstanding debt at the end of 2009, estimates Victor Shih, an economist at Northwestern University and the author of "Factions and Finance in China." That's equal to about 35% of China's GDP in 2009.

In addition, banks have agreed to an additional $1.9 trillion in credit lines for local investment companies that the companies haven't yet drawn down, Shih says.

Together the debt plus the credit lines come to $3.8 trillion. That's roughly equal to 75% of China's GDP.

None of this, Shih points out, is included in the IMF calculation of China's gross-debt-to-GDP figure of 22%. If it were, the number would be closer to 100%.


Savings aplenty, but for whom?
Exactly how important is this number?

It depends on how many of those loans at local investment companies will go bad. Shih estimates that about 25% of current outstanding loans -- totalling $439 billion -- will go bad. (For comparison, remember that in the aftermath of the 1997 currency crisis, the newly established asset management companies swallowed $287 billion in bad loans.)

It also depends on how much of China's huge reserves and huge base of personal savings are available to offset the debt. So far, I've been talking about gross debt. But China, like Japan, has a huge domestic pool of savings it can use to buy debt. Economists point out that Japan has carried what looks like a crippling gross-debt-to-GDP ratio for years -- 188% in 2007, 197% in 2008, 219% (estimated) in 2009, and 227% (projected) in 2010 -- without disaster, because the country funds its debt internally from savings.

China, the argument goes, could easily do the same, so what's the problem?

The problem for both China and Japan is that it's not clear exactly how much of their huge pools of domestic savings are actually available in the long run to buy debt. Japan has a woefully underfunded retirement system, and it's by no means clear how the population of the world's most rapidly aging country is going to pay for retirement.

China has, for all intents and purposes, no public retirement system. As a result of its one-child policy, the country has also begun to age quickly, and by 2030 its population will be as old as that of the United States.

In the U.S., the national accounts may lie about the effect of the problem by putting Social Security and Medicare off-budget on the argument that, since these programs have their own dedicated revenue streams, they don't count as part of the national debt. But that lie aside, because the benefits of these programs are defined, it is possible to put a dollar figure on the government's future liabilities in this area (with all the uncertainty that comes with forecasting inflation, of course).

China isn't hiding any future liability for pensions or retiree health care off the books. The government hasn't promised future payments. In an accounting sense, then, there is no future liability that ought to be on the nation's books.

But that doesn't mean China won't have to consume some portion of its accumulated savings to pay for its post-65 population in 2030. The country, either through the government or through private citizens, will have to cover the costs of old age, however it defines that cost. And any savings it will use to pay for those costs really aren't available now to pay current debts.

I think the Chinese leadership is profoundly aware of the need today to not waste money that the country will need tomorrow. That's one reason Beijing has taken steps recently to rein in local investment companies. On March 8, the Ministry of Finance announced plans to nullify all guarantees by local governments for loans taken out by their investment company vehicles. And the national government plans to sell $29 billion in bonds for local governments this year, giving those governments an alternative to setting up local investment companies.

But the big job -- the reform of China's tax system so that local governments don't have to rely on real-estate and stock-market bubbles for funding -- didn't make it on the to-do list announced by the National People's Congress this week and last. And I don't think it's likely to with Communist Party leaders jockeying for position to replace President Hu Jintao and Premier Wen Jiabao in 2012. (For more on the effect of politics on economics in China, see this blog post.)

By the time China's leadership team has sorted itself out in 2013, China's finances will certainly look different. There's little chance they'll look better.

Jim Jubak has been writing Jubak's Journal and tracking the performance of his market-beating Jubak's Picks portfolio since 1997 on MSN Money. He is the author of a new book, "The Jubak Picks," and writer of the Jubak Picks blog. He's also the senior markets editor at MoneyShow.com.
 
On a related note - from the Daily Telegraph (a notable Left Wing rag praised world-wide by Guardianistas)
Ambrose Evans-Pritchard

....We have talked ourselves into believing that China is already a hyper-power. It may become one: it is not one yet. China is ringed by states - Japan, Korea, Vietnam, India - that are American allies when push comes to shove. It faces a prickly Russia on its 4,000km border, where Chinese migrants are itching for Lebensraum across the Amur. Emerging Asia, Brazil, Egypt and Europe are all irked by China's yuan-rigged export dumping.

Michael Pettis from Beijing University argues that China's reserves of $2.4 trillion - arguably $3 trillion - are a sign of weakness, not strength. Only twice before in modern history has a country amassed such a stash equal to 5pc-6pc of global GDP: the US in the 1920s, and Japan in the 1980s. Each time preceeded depression.

The reserves cannot be used internally to support China's economy. They are dead weight, beyond any level needed for macro-credibility. Indeed, they are the ultimate indictment of China's dysfunctional strategy, which is to buy $30bn to $40bn of foreign bonds every month to hold down the yuan, refusing to let the economy adjust to trade realities. The result is over-investment in plant, flooding the world with goods at wafer-thin export margins. China's over-capacity in steel is now greater than Europe's output.

This is catching up with China, in any case. Professor Victor Shuh from Northerwestern University warns that the 8,000 financing vehicles used by China's local governments to stretch credit limits have built up debts and commitments of $3.5 trillion, mostly linked to infrastructure. He says the banks may require a bail-out nearing half a trillion dollars.

As America's creditor - owner of some $1.4 trillion of US Treasuries, agency bonds, and US instruments - China can exert leverage. But this is not what it seems. If the Politburo deploys its illusiory power, Washington can pull the plug on China's export economy instantly by shutting markets. Who holds whom to ransom?

Any attempt to retaliate by triggering a US bond crisis would rebound against China, and could be stopped - in extremis - by capital controls. Roosevelt changed the rules in 1933. Such things happen. The China-US relationship is no doubt symbiotic, but a clash would not be "mutual assured destruction", as often claimed. Washington would win.

Contrary to myth, the slide to protectionism after the 1930 Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act did not cause the Depression. Trade contracted more slowly in the 1930s than this time. The Smoot-Hawley lesson is that tariffs have asymmetrical effects. They devastate surplus countries: then America. Deficit Britain did well by retreating into Imperial Preference.

Barack Obama has never exalted free trade. This orthodoxy is, in any case, under threat in the West. His top economic adviser Larry Summers let drop in Davos that free-trade arguments no longer hold when dealing with "mercantilist" powers. Adam Smith recognized this too...

 
The headline above as predicted by the world's current richest man, Mexican telephone magnate and billionaire Carlos Slim.

Forbes link

(...)

Slim's bold prediction for the decade: "Latin America is close to breaking the underdevelopment barrier, of around US$12,000 of income per capita. It seems to me that this should happen in the next 10 years."

He continues: "The developing countries in Latin America have available both internal and external financial resources, better terms of trade on their exports of primary goods and competitive advantages thanks to the availability and production of commodities, tourism and a modern industrial sector."

Not everyone is as bullish. After several decades of tepid growth, Latin America's economy is expected to expand between 3% and 4.5% in 2010.

The more optimistic economists, however, argue that the region's growth will be buttressed by a multitude of factors weighing in Latin America's favor. Unlike its more developed counterparts, the region only experienced collateral damage from the credit crunch.

"Latin America has bounced back strongly," says Jerome Booth, head of research at Ashmore Investment Management. "Latin America's banks are already taking market share from U.S. and European competitors." That's more good news for Slim, who has a 55% stake in Inbursa Bank, one of Mexico's largest financial firms.

Slim says the dichotomy between the developed and emerging worlds will be amplified in the coming years, as developed economies continue to wrestle with their "financial systems, fiscal and financial deficits and their transition to a society of advanced services in which excessive imports of goods are not compensated by other revenues and have to be financed by foreign savings
."
(...)
 
A hundred years ago, or thereabouts, the same prediction was quite realistic. Argentina, Brazil and Chile were booming, by any and all standards; but the Latin American propensity for political and economic self destruction asserted itself. I remain confident it will do so again.
 
So far we have looked at public debt. (A lot of unfunded liabilities like pensions and benefits are not even listed in these calculations, in the US alone it is estimated that there is a 2 trillion dollar shortfall for unionized State and Municipal employee pensions and benefits). Private debt is another drag on the economy (since resources are not available for private investment or consumption). Don't think things are roses for Canada:

http://globaleconomicanalysis.blogspot.com/2010/03/canadian-credit-bubble-in-pictures.html

Canadian Credit Bubble In Pictures

Here are 4 images from Jonathan Tonge at America-Canada Blog regarding Canada, The Country of Fiscal Prudence

Credit Card Debt Up $43 Billion Since 1999



Personal Lines of Credit Up $180 Billion Since 1999



Mortgage Debt Up $566 Billion Since 1999



Household Credit Up $715 Billion Since 1999



See the above link for more details.

Think there is no credit bubble in Canada? Think again.

Mike "Mish" Shedlock
http://globaleconomicanalysis.blogspot.com

 
Given the huge size and potential growth of "carbon trading", this sort of instability will have serious consequences (especially with the industries forced to "buy" carbon credits in the first place). Add the frauds being pulled on the carbon trading market (see the Global Warming superthread) and political manipulation and you have the making of a perfect storm:

http://business.timesonline.co.uk/tol/business/industry_sectors/natural_resources/article7066315.ece

Chaos on carbon market over ‘recycled’ permits
Carl Mortished: World Business Editor

    * 6 Comments

Recommend? (5)

Europe’s emissions trading system was in uproar yesterday amid a mounting scandal over “recycled” carbon permits.

Two carbon exchanges were forced to suspend trading as panic hit investors fearful that they had bought invalid permits.

BlueNext and Nord Pool, the French and Nordic exchanges, suspended trading in certificates of emission reduction (CERs) when it emerged that some had been illegally reused.

Concern that used and worthless permits were circulating caused the spot price of the certificates to collapse, from €12 per tonne of carbon to less than €1 .
Related Links

    * One burning question, no easy answers

    * European carbon trading market takes hit

The scare erupted after Hungary said last week that it had sold 2 million CERs submitted by Hungarian companies to satisfy their carbon emission allowances under the EU’s emission trading system (ETS).

Carbon permits submitted by companies every year to the national register are usually cancelled. However, Hungary exploited a loophole that allows CERs — which are issued not by European Union governments but by the United Nations under its Clean Development Mechanism — to be traded.

Investors in the carbon market took fright as it emerged that some of the Hungarian CERs had found their way back into the market, despite having been used to meet the carbon targets of Hungarian companies.

The double counting is threatening confidence in the ETS, according to staff at one energy consultancy. Icis Heren said: “For companies obliged by law to buy carbon credits ... government-led carbon credit recycling means they risk buying a worthless asset.”

The Hungarian Government said that the used CERs were sold to non-European investors, but BlueNext said that it had found some of the suspect CERs trading on its system.

The ETS, which was intended to create a market incentive for companies to reduce their carbon emissions, has suffered from repeated crises of confidence. At first, too many carbon allowances, known as EUAs, were issued by individual governments, creating a glut and a collapse in the price of carbon.

Efforts to tighten up the market have been stymied by recession, which has reduced Europe’s overall CO2 output and kept the carbon price low.

Meanwhile, suspicion has dogged the parallel trade in CERs, which are similar to EUAs but issued by the UN to companies that invest in renewable energy projects in the developing world.

A proportion of these CERs can be used by European companies as currency within the emission-trading scheme to top up their supply of carbon permits.

However, the Hungarian Government’s exploitation of the loophole to sell on used CERs to raise cash has created confusion about supply and demand in the system and has cast further doubt on the carbon trading market.
 
We are in a period of unstable equilibrium. The market hasn't cleared billions or trillions of dollars in overvalued assets. If that were to happen, we could see deflation on a massive scale (the Great Depression of the 20th century had it's initial start as the huge monetary inflation of the First World War got cleared). On the other hand, governments the world over are turning their currency into monopoly money, the conditions that lead to inflation and hyper inflation.

These are actions you can take if you believe that inflation or hyper inflation is possible or likely. I would suggest that these steps taken in moderation might still be useful: (FWD via email)

What steps can I take to prevent losing everything in a crash? Avoid debt? … significant assets in banks … will all just evaporate during a hyperinflation episode … what would a prudent person do?

Welll… Market crash and hyperinflation can be different scenarios.
Not mutually exclusive, but you can have one without the other; though hyperinflation tends to produce a market crash eventually.
If you are certain that hyperinflation is coming then the rational (though arguably not ethical) response would be:
1) Liquidate all savings.
2) Borrow as much as you can; at fixed rates.
3) Borrow more. At fixed rates.
4) Seriously, fixed rates: don’t screw that step up.
5) Do not loan anything; that includes any savings accounts (= loan to bank), corporate or treasury bonds, etc.
6) Put all your investment in assets of proven inherent value: gold, commodities etc (physical goods if possible).
7) Better yet invest in productive assets of proven value. Rentable land, farmland probably better than housing/retail/office; mines; oil; physical infrastructure etc. Owning directly rather than via a corporation probably better still.
8) Sit back and let hyperinflation write down your debts, while real assets hold value.
9) Don’t come crying to me when this leaves you flat bust if hyperinflation doesn’t happen.
 
Regulatory failure indeed:

http://www.city-journal.org/2010/eon0318gs.html

The Euro in Crisis
In Greece and elsewhere, statism proves riskier than free markets.
18 March 2010

The financial crisis of 2008, still far from over, has done severe damage to the reputation of the free market. The crisis, we are assured, was caused by the withdrawal of the state and an excess of deregulation. To get out of it will thus require a massive return to public spending and intervention, which is in fact what we see happening all over Europe and in the United States. However, what we might call the Greek affair should make us question the statist solution. We ought to consider the possibility that public management could prove even more dangerous than private—that state regulation is no less chancy than deregulation.

The duplicity and corruption of Greek public accounting was more than an error of bookkeeping. The concealment of the country’s real budget deficit necessarily involved a gigantic network of complicity that included the whole political class, the state bureaucracy, and the banks. This network was not confined to Greece: it included Greece’s European partners, Europe’s political leaders, the governors of the Eurozone, the directors of the European Central Bank, and the European Commission. It’s hard to believe that the European Commission’s Directorate General for Economic and Financial Affairs was ignorant of what was really happening in Greece; and it will come as a surprise to some but not others that Eurostat, the statistical institute of the European Commission, has for years been publishing deliberately false numbers that make the phony accounting of the ratings agencies implicated in the 2008 financial crisis pale in comparison.

What was the motive for all this deception? Obviously, to give credibility to the euro, a common currency supposed to rival the American dollar. Recall that the theoretical virtue of the euro is to bring down interest rates in Europe: the more solid the money, the lower the rates, which encourages economic development (or, in the case of Spain and Portugal, real-estate speculation). It was therefore much to Europe’s advantage to cover for Greece and protect the euro.

What’s telling is that the people who brought the hoax to light were neither the Greek nor the European authorities but private speculators. The Greek state, to its great dismay, suddenly discovered that it could no longer sell treasury bonds on financial markets at the same rate as the Germans did. The open market had decided that euros owned by Greeks were not the same as euros owned by Germans. Should we blame these private actors for exposing the truth? On the contrary: it was their professional duty to generate profits for their clients, often for their retirement accounts. The public actors, for their part, were duty-bound in principle to manage the euro through predictable and transparent rules. It is therefore inappropriate for French president Nicolas Sarkozy and Greek prime minister George Papandreou to accuse private speculators of “attacking” the euro. If the euro—at least in Greek hands—had been above suspicion, it would not have been attacked.

Beyond the Greek affair, moreover, it’s suddenly evident that the Eurozone as a whole suffers from awful public management. Not a single government in the Eurozone (Germany remaining the most virtuous, to be sure) respects the two requirements that the euro theoretically imposes on states using it: a public deficit that’s less than 3 percent of GDP and a public debt that’s less than 60 percent of the same. After Greece, the states with the largest debts are Ireland, Spain, and Italy, followed by a second group that includes France and Portugal.

How did the Eurozone become so badly managed and, in the end, so unpredictable? Adverse local traditions—the spendthrift state in France, the lying state in Greece—endured, and a Keynesian catastrophe compounded them. In the name of crisis management, Keynesian ideology led to a sort of renationalization of the European economy. Perhaps the return of statism helped prevent a deeper depression; we’ll never know for sure, because the Great Crisis never happened. But what has been proven, at least to a high degree of probability, is that the renewed energies of statism have left behind a fragile euro and unmanageable public debt. The United States should take no comfort in the euro’s problems, by the way. The leading credit-ratings agencies have just warned that they may downgrade American debt—unsurprisingly, since all Western countries that follow the Keynesian road flirt with bankruptcy. We are all Greeks now.

Economics can be a cruel science because it offers a choice between imperfect solutions. On the one hand, markets are unpredictable—and vulnerable to speculative crises and private failures—but they lead, on the whole, to general development, as history has amply demonstrated. On the other hand, public intervention offers short-term security but generates risks more serious than those of market uncertainty—namely public debt, inflation, and stagnation. The usual choice in economics is not between good and evil but between more evil and less. The path is narrow but known.

Guy Sorman, a City Journal contributing editor, is the author of numerous books, including Economics Does Not Lie.
 
It looks like the financial crisis is causing a political crisis in the EU:

http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/comment/ambroseevans_pritchard/7494718/Has-Germany-just-killed-the-dream-of-a-European-superstate.html

Has Germany just killed the dream of a European superstate?

So after weeks of Euro-bluff it looks ever more like an IMF rescue for Greece after all, and hence for any other eurozone nation driven to ruin by the wrong monetary policy.


By Ambrose Evans-Pritchard
Published: 7:29PM GMT 21 Mar 2010


German Chancellor Angela Merkel has little hope of selling a bail-out of Greece to German voters

German and Dutch leaders have concluded in the nick of time that they cannot defy the will of their sovereign parliaments by propping up a country that lied about its deficits, or risk court defeats by breaching the no-bail-out clause in Article 125 of the EU Treaties.

Chancellor Angela Merkel has halted at the Rubicon. So has Dutch premier Jan Peter Balkenende, as well he might in charge of a broken government facing elections in a country where far-right leader Geert Wilders is the second political force, and where the Tweede Kamer has categorically blocked loans for Greece.

The failure of EU leaders to cobble together a plausible bail-out – if that is what occurs at this week’s Brussels summit – is a 'game-changer' in market parlance. Eurogroup chair Jean-Claude Juncker said last month that such an outcome would shatter the credibility of monetary union. It certainly shatters many assumptions.

There will be no inevitable move to fiscal federalism; no EU treasury or economic government; no debt union. It is Stalingrad for the federalist camp and the institutions of the permanent EU government.

I remember hearing Joschka Fischer, then German Vice-Chancellor, telling Euro-MPs a decade ago that EMU was “a quantum leap ... creating an inexorable federal logic”. Such views were in vogue then.

Any euro crisis would force Europe to create the necessary machinery to make it work, acting as a catalyst for full-fledged union. Yet the moment of truth has come. There is no quantum leap. We have a Merkel pirouette.

Paris is watching nervously. As Le Monde put it last week, “behind the question of aid to Greece is a France-Germany match that pitches two conceptions of Europe against each other.” The game is not going well for 'Les Bleus’. The whole point of the euro for the Quai D’Orsay was to lock Germany into economic fusion. Instead we have fission.

EU leaders may yet rustle up a rescue package that keeps the IMF at bay, but alliances are shifting fast. Even Italy has slipped into the pro-IMF camp, knowing that rescue costs can be shifted on to the US, Japan, Britain, Russia, China, and the Saudis, lessening the burden for Rome.

Besides, too much has been said over the last week that cannot be unsaid. Mrs Merkel’s speech to the Bundestag was epochal, a defiant warning that henceforth Germany would pursue the German national interest in EU affairs, capped by her call for treaty changes to allow the expulsion of fiscal sinners from Euroland. Nothing seems so permanent about the euro any more.

Days later, Thilo Sarrazin from the Bundesbank blurted out that if Greece cannot pay its bills “it should do what every debtor has to do and file for insolvency. This would be a suitably frightening example for every other potentially unsound state,” he said, pointedly excluding France from the list of sound countries.

Dr Sarrazin should be locked up in a Frankfurt Sanatorium. It was such flippancy that led to the Lehman disaster, requiring state rescues of half the world’s financial system. A Greek default would alone be twice the size of the combined defaults by Argentina and Russia. Contagion across Club Med would instantly set off a second banking crisis.

Some suspect that ultra-hawks in Germany want to bring the EMU crisis to a head, deeming delay to be the greater danger. How else to interpret last week’s speech by Jürgen Stark, Germany’s man at the European Central Bank, calling for tightening to head off inflation.

This is alarming. Core inflation in Euroland was 0.9pc in February, the lowest since the data series began. It is certain to fall further as the doubling of oil prices fades from the base effect. M3 money has been contracting for a year. Business credit is shrinking at a 2.7pc rate.

So, it is not enough for the EU to impose a fiscal squeeze of 10pc of GDP on Greece, 8pc on Spain, and 6pc on Portugal, and 5pc on France over three years, we need a dose of 1930s monetary policy as well to make sure life is Hell for everybody.

Be that as it may, Greece’s George Papandreou says his country is in the worst of both worlds, suffering IMF-style austerity without receiving IMF money – which comes cheap at around 3.25pc. So why allow his country to be used as a “guinea pig” – as he put it - by EU factions pursuing conflicting agendas?

The IMF option has its limits too. The maximum ever lent by the Fund is 12 times quota, or €15bn for Greece, not enough to nurse the country through to June. The standard IMF cure of devaluation is blocked by euro membership. So Greece will have to sweat it out with a public debt spiralling to 135pc of GDP next year, stuck in slump with no exit route.

The deeper truth that few care to face is that under the current EMU structure Berlin will have to do for Greece and Club Med what it has done for East Germany, pay vast subsidies for decades. Events of the last week have made it clear that no such money will ever be forthcoming.

Let me be clear. I do not blame Greece, Ireland, Italy, or Spain for what has happened. No central bank could have tried more heroically than the Banco d’España to counter the effects of negative real interest rates, but the macro-policy error of monetary union washed over its efforts.

Nor do I blame Germany, which generously agreed to give up the D-Mark to keep the political peace. It was the price that France demanded in exchange for tolerating reunification after the Berlin Wall came down.

I blame the EU elites that charged ahead with this project for the wrong reasons – some cynically, mostly out of Hegelian absolutism – ignoring the economic anthropology of Europe and the rules of basic common sense. They must answer for a depression.
 
Status
Not open for further replies.
Back
Top